The
road to pension liberalization was largely necessitated by unsustainable
pension systems in Ghana. While the social insurance of family ties is
weakening in recent times, the formal pension system prior to 2008 was like
HIV/AIDS as described in some academic publications; meaning it was a
slow-but-sure killer. The history of pensions in Ghana is marked by inadequate
pension income, corruption and mismanagement. During this period, the pension
system had just one pillar, which was a define benefit (DB) scheme. A DB scheme
is a promise by a sponsor (in this case government) bearing responsibility to
pay a fixed life annuity; sometimes inflation-adjusted and benefits are a
function of both years of service and wage history. Since DB schemes enables the pooling and
group management of funds, it provides risk-sharing properties that are not
captured by Defined Contribution (individual pension accounts) models. However,
they were unfunded, in that funds were not set aside for the payment of
pensions; rather, pensions were paid from tax revenue whenever due; thus,
earning the name pay-as-you-go pension.
The
growing number of pensioners and slow economic growth increased the cost of
pensions to the government and practically made it unsustainable to maintain an
unfunded one pillar DB pension system. It is within this pension
sustainability debate that the almighty concept of liberalism, which has gain
grounds since the 1980s due to what was referred to as the “the crisis of the
welfare state” in the west and the “weakness of post-colonialist bureaucracies”
infected global pension schemes. In simple terms, pension liberalism implies
the privatization of pensions and retirement planning mainly through Defined
contribution (DC) schemes. In this wake and championed by the World Bank in a
report entitled “Averting the old Age Crisis”, a three-pillar pension scheme
including a mixture of DB and DC schemes were proposed to salvage the looming global
pension crisis. Although the World Bank
didn’t make a direct contribution as argued by Kpessa (2011), its ideology was
lingering in the mind of the Bediako Committee that undertook the pension
reform in Ghana. Hence, the reason for the current three-pillar pension system
in Ghana.
In
this article, which is Part I of these series, I wish to share with readers some
insights into the inherent risk of the neoliberal new three-pillar pension
system in Ghana, which we shall refer to as “diversification risk”. This risk potentially exist as a result of the separation of the management of first and
second mandatory pension contributions. While the separation of the management
function provides diversification benefits, it also engenders risk given the
high level of financial illiteracy in Ghana. Therefore, to borrow the words of
the English Poet John Keat (1819), the separation process embodies the “Contrarieties of Life: the Irreconcilable
but Inseparable Opposites of Life” – where there is life, there is death.
In this case, its advantages could be in itself a disadvantage from a portfolio
management perspective. This implies that merely dividing the pension system
into three tiers does not necessarily mean diversification although one of the
goals of the new multi-pillar pension system in Ghana (Kpessa, 2013; 2011;
World Bank, 1994). I will work through some simple estimations to demonstrate
the phenomenon of diversification risk. The rest of the article will focus on
describing the latent diversification risk in our new pension system and how it could manifest
and be magnified by financial illiteracy and information asymmetry – unequal
information among economic agents; i.e. pension fund managers and pension
contributors who make investment decisions.
The
Bediako Commission set up in 2004 led to the enactment of the current National
Pension Act, 2004 (Act 766) to introduce a contributory three-tier pension
scheme to provide improved retirement benefits for all workers. The ACT
requires employers to contribute 13% and workers 5.5% of gross income, making a
total contribution of 18.5%. This distribution is presented below:
a.
First
tier basic national social security (defined benefit –DB) (13% out of total
contributions); which is managed by the Social Security and National Investment Trust (SSNIT) is mandatory for all employees in
both the private and public sectors. 2.5% out of 13% is a levy for the National
Health Insurance scheme;
b.
Second
tier mandatory occupational (or work-based) “defined contribution (DC)” pension scheme (5% out of total
contribution) is “fully funded” by
employees and privately-managed by approved Trustees assisted by Pension Fund
Managers and Custodians. It is designed primarily to give contributors lump sum
benefits.
c.
Third
tier voluntary provident fund and personal pension schemes, supported by tax
benefit incentives for workers in the informal (blue collar) and formal sectors
(white collar).
The
three tiers (pillars) of the new pension system constitute a portfolio of
pension investments, which has investment diversification as one of its goals. Under
section 176 – Permitted Investments, pension fund managers have nine classes of
investments to choose from, which broadly cover a host of capital market and
money market investments. These include shares (ordinary and preferential),
bonds (government and corporate), Treasury bills, investment funds like mutual
funds and unit trusts, debt securities and real estate, etc. Each of these
investments have unique risk and return profiles (behaviours) and are likely to
provide diversification benefits as investment portfolio management requires.
The principle of diversification implies putting your eggs in different baskets,
so that in the event of loss, some baskets of eggs (investments) may be saved.
In other words, as one basket of investments is doing well, another may be
doing badly, so that the performance of the latter is compensated for by the
former. Therefore the average (mean) return is the expectation of the investor.
Where all investments are put in one basket, the mean is the same as the total return
on the one basket of investment, which may increase the risk of the investment portfolio without commensurate return.
Diversification Risk
and the Separation of the Pension Management Function
Diversification
is thus effective when selected investments behave differently. In the one
basket investment scenario above, all the investments behave the same and
likely to provide little or no diversification potential. However, in the
different investment basket scenario, diversification is likely to be
maximized; i.e. returned maximized and risk reduced. Diversification is most
effective when the pension fund manager has perfect information about the
investment types he/she is investing in. In that case, he/she may not put all
his eggs in one basket. A statistical measure of diversification is the correlation of returns, which measures the relationship between investment assets returns. The lower the correlation, the better the diversification potential; so zero and negative correlations may provide better diversification than positive correlations between assets. A zero correlation means that there is no relationship between the return behaviour of the portfolio of investments. A negative correlation means a negative relationship, so that when the returns on one asset (A) is moving up, the return on asset (B) is falling and vice versa, which is preferred. A position correlation indicates that returns are moving in the same direction, which is mostly not preferred. diversification therefore minimizes the volatility (risk) of asset returns whiles maximizing returns.
Although the new pension system is restructured and obviously divided (diversified) into three different baskets of investments, the benefits of diversification may be elusive as the separation of the management function comes with “information asymmetry” among pension fund managers. In this vein, the first tier DB social security scheme is managed by the SSNIT; the second tier DC will be managed by pension fund managers appointed by pension trustees on behalf of pension contributors; and the third tier by the NTHC as proposed. Since, the latter is voluntary, we will focus on the first and second mandatory schemes from here.
Although the new pension system is restructured and obviously divided (diversified) into three different baskets of investments, the benefits of diversification may be elusive as the separation of the management function comes with “information asymmetry” among pension fund managers. In this vein, the first tier DB social security scheme is managed by the SSNIT; the second tier DC will be managed by pension fund managers appointed by pension trustees on behalf of pension contributors; and the third tier by the NTHC as proposed. Since, the latter is voluntary, we will focus on the first and second mandatory schemes from here.
Private
pension fund managers are experts in investing in particular financial
instruments, say bonds or shares or real estate. Despite their expertise, the
likelihood that they may lack information about SSNIT’s investments of the
first tier DB funds cannot be compromise. Hence, the separation of the
management function as a result of neoliberalism (privatization) potentially
could create unequal information (asymmetry) between SSNIT and private pension
fund managers of the second tier, which could have the effect of compromising
the benefit of diversification as required by having different baskets of
investments. In other words, although the structure of new pension system is
diversified in theory, diversification in practice may be unachievable because
the managers of the two different baskets of investments, SSNIT (first tier)
and private pension fund managers (second tier) may invest in the same
investments, say bonds or shares or real estate at the same time. In effect,
they may end up putting all of contributors’ contributions in one investment
basket. The failure of this one investment basket means that everything fails
unlike a situation where investing in different assets may save some. For the
purpose of understanding the concept of diversification risk, I will discuss
two scenarios; (1) an undiversified portfolio and (2) a diversified portfolio.
For
instance, if SSNIT and the private pension fund managers invested in the same real
estate investment vehicle, which produced a return of zero (0%), then the SSNIT
will receive zero (0%) and the private pension funds also zero (0%). The total
and average returns are both zero (0%); [i.e. 0% + 0% = 0% and (0% + 0%/2) =
0/2 undefined]. This is the worst case scenario of an undiversified portfolio. However,
if SSNIT invested in real estate and the private pension fund managers invested
in bonds which yields zero (0%) and 5% respectively, then the average of the
investments’ returns [i.e. (0% + 5%)/2 = 2.5%], which is 2.5% is what a
contributor will earn. A contributor’s total return will be 5%, i.e. 0% + 5% in
the diversification scenario. Thus, the low performance of real estate is
offset by a positive high performance in bonds.
Besides,
the effect described above is not exactly as it will be, given that SSNIT’s
investments are guaranteed by government; so irrespective of returns on their
investment, government must provide a positive above zero return to
contributors. Thus, government’s guarantee mitigates investment risk – the risk
that the investment will fail. This is because pension pay-outs from the
first tier DB scheme is not market determined but by a formula which
incorporates the length of service and contribution rate (how much a
contributor saved with the government). Hence, using the same undiversified
scenario above, if real estate yields zero (0%), the private pension funds and
for that matter contributors will receive 0% but the contributor will not
receive 0% from government guaranteed SSNIT managed pension funds. This is
because governments as mentioned above usually commit (guaranteed) to pay a
minimum return to contributors on its borrowings from the SSNIT; say 2% above
inflation. In this case, the total
return becomes 2%; [i.e. 0% + 2%] and the average return [i.e. (0% + 2%)/2]
will be 1%, which is better than the first undiversified scenario without
government guarantee above.
The
picture is even better with diversified portfolios with government guarantee of
2% minimum return above inflation. To illustrate this with the first
diversified scenario, if market returns of SSNITs investment in real estate is
zero (0%) but the private pension fund managers earn 5% from investing in
bonds, then the total return and average return will be 7% and 3.5% [ i.e. 2% +
5% = 7% and (2% + 5%/2%) = 3.5%] respectively. This example is particularly
important because it demonstrates that the “unguaranteed” privately managed
second tier pension scheme should be watched closely with both eyes since
returns (real) could be practically zero and even negative because returns are
determined by market forces, which are volatile and uncertain. The phenomenon
of diversification without diversification (“diversification risk” trap) fuelled
by information asymmetry may exist in all multi-pillar pension systems, even in
the advanced economies.
In
Part II of these series, I will look at how “financial
illiteracy” among pension contributors and “their right to make investment choices in the second tier defined
contribution scheme” could manifest and magnify the diversification risk potentially
inherent in the new multi-pillar pension system in Ghana.
Kenneth A.
Donkor-Hyiaman
kwakuhyiaman@gmail.com